icon picker
Managing the Commons

Elinor Ostrom was an American political economist and the first woman to receive the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2009. She is known for her work on the management of common-pool resources, such as forests, fisheries, and water systems, which are shared by many individuals.
Ostrom's research challenged the conventional wisdom that common-pool resources would inevitably be overused and depleted due to the tragedy of the commons, where individuals acting in their own self-interest would ultimately destroy the resource. Instead, Ostrom found that communities have developed a variety of institutions and mechanisms to manage these resources sustainably and prevent overuse.
Ostrom identified eight design principles that are commonly found in successful commons management systems:
Clearly defined boundaries: the resource system and the users are clearly defined. Proportional equivalence: rules and benefits are balanced and match the needs and conditions of the resource system and its users. Collective choice arrangements: users have a say in how the resource is used and managed. Monitoring: users monitor each other's behavior to ensure compliance with the rules. Graduated sanctions: penalties for non-compliance escalate over time, providing an incentive to follow the rules. Fast and fair conflict resolution: mechanisms exist to resolve conflicts between users quickly and fairly. Local autonomy: users have the ability to self-organize and make their own rules. Polycentric governance: multiple layers of authority and decision-making exist, from local to regional to national levels.
Ostrom's work emphasized the importance of local knowledge, trust, and cooperation in the management of common-pool resources. She argued that successful commons management requires a balance between individual freedom and collective responsibility, and that a variety of institutional arrangements can be effective in achieving this balance.
Ostrom's ideas have had a significant impact on the field of environmental governance and have influenced policy and practice around the world. Her work provides a valuable framework for understanding how communities can manage common-pool resources sustainably, and offers practical guidance for policymakers and practitioners seeking to design effective governance systems.
The first design principle identified by Elinor Ostrom for successful management of common-pool resources is clearly defined boundaries. This principle emphasizes the importance of clearly defining the resource system and the users who are authorized to use it.
Clear boundaries help to create a sense of identity and shared responsibility among users, which in turn can promote cooperation and coordination in the management of the resource. When boundaries are not clearly defined, it can lead to confusion and conflict over who has the right to use the resource and how it should be managed. This can result in overuse and depletion of the resource, as users may take more than their fair share in an effort to secure access.
The boundaries should be defined in a way that is meaningful and relevant to the resource system and its users. For example, in the case of a fishery, the boundaries could be defined by the geographic area where the fish live or by the type of gear that is used to catch the fish. The boundaries should also be clear and easily recognizable to all users, to prevent accidental or intentional encroachment.
Effective boundaries are often created through a combination of formal rules and informal norms. Formal rules might include legal frameworks that define property rights, while informal norms might include social norms and cultural traditions that define appropriate behavior and usage patterns. Effective boundaries may also involve the creation of user groups or associations that are responsible for managing the resource and enforcing rules.
Overall, the first design principle of clearly defined boundaries emphasizes the importance of creating a sense of identity and shared responsibility among resource users, which can promote cooperation and coordination in the sustainable management of common-pool resources.


The second design principle identified by Elinor Ostrom for successful management of common-pool resources is proportional equivalence. This principle emphasizes the importance of designing rules and regulations that are proportional to the needs and conditions of the resource system and its users.
Proportional equivalence means that the costs and benefits of using the resource should be distributed fairly among users, and that the rules and regulations should be tailored to the specific needs and conditions of the resource system. This ensures that users are incentivized to use the resource sustainably and that the benefits of doing so are shared fairly among all users.
For example, in the case of a fishery, proportional equivalence might mean designing rules that limit the total amount of fish that can be caught each season, or that restrict the types of fishing gear that can be used to prevent overfishing. The costs of enforcing these rules might be distributed among all users, but the benefits of sustainable fishing practices (e.g., higher fish populations, more stable incomes) would also be shared among all users.
Proportional equivalence can also mean adjusting rules and regulations to reflect changes in the resource system or the needs of its users over time. For example, if the fish population in a particular area begins to decline, it may be necessary to adjust the rules governing fishing practices to ensure that the resource is not overused.
Overall, the principle of proportional equivalence emphasizes the importance of designing rules and regulations that are tailored to the specific needs and conditions of the resource system and its users. By doing so, it can help ensure that the costs and benefits of using the resource are distributed fairly and that users are incentivized to use the resource sustainably over the long-term.

The third design principle identified by Elinor Ostrom for successful management of common-pool resources is collective choice arrangements. This principle emphasizes the importance of giving resource users a say in how the resource is used and managed.
Collective choice arrangements involve creating a mechanism for resource users to participate in decision-making processes related to the management of the resource. This can take many different forms, including formal voting systems, informal consensus-building processes, or the creation of user committees or associations.
By giving resource users a say in how the resource is used and managed, collective choice arrangements can help to create a sense of ownership and shared responsibility among users. This can, in turn, promote cooperation and coordination in the sustainable management of the resource.
For example, in the case of a community forest, collective choice arrangements might involve creating a user committee or association that is responsible for making decisions related to the use and management of the forest. This committee might be made up of representatives from different user groups (e.g., loggers, hunters, gatherers), and decisions might be made through a consensus-building process.
Collective choice arrangements can also help to ensure that decisions related to the management of the resource are informed by local knowledge and experience. By involving resource users in the decision-making process, managers can tap into the expertise and insights of those who are most familiar with the resource system and its intricacies.
Overall, the third design principle of collective choice arrangements emphasizes the importance of involving resource users in decision-making processes related to the management of the resource. By doing so, it can help to create a sense of ownership and shared responsibility among users, promote cooperation and coordination in the sustainable management of the resource, and ensure that decisions are informed by local knowledge and experience.


The fourth design principle identified by Elinor Ostrom for successful management of common-pool resources is monitoring. This principle emphasizes the importance of monitoring resource use and conditions to ensure that rules and regulations are being followed and that the resource is being managed sustainably.
Monitoring can take many different forms, including regular inspections, reporting requirements, and the use of remote sensing technologies. The goal of monitoring is to ensure that resource users are complying with rules and regulations, and to identify potential problems or threats to the resource system before they become critical.
By monitoring resource use and conditions, managers can also identify trends and patterns in resource use that may require adjustments to rules and regulations. For example, if monitoring data shows that a particular user group is consistently overusing the resource, managers may need to adjust rules and regulations to ensure that the resource is not depleted.
Effective monitoring systems also involve clear and transparent reporting mechanisms, so that all users have access to information about the condition of the resource and the actions being taken to manage it. This can help to build trust among users and promote cooperation in the sustainable management of the resource.
For example, in the case of a community irrigation system, monitoring might involve regular inspections of the system to ensure that water is being used efficiently and that the system is being maintained properly. Users might be required to report their water use on a regular basis, and this information might be made available to all users to promote transparency and accountability.
Overall, the fourth design principle of monitoring emphasizes the importance of monitoring resource use and conditions to ensure that rules and regulations are being followed and that the resource is being managed sustainably. By doing so, it can help to identify potential problems or threats to the resource system before they become critical, and ensure that adjustments to rules and regulations are made in a timely and transparent manner.

The fifth design principle identified by Elinor Ostrom for successful management of common-pool resources is graduated sanctions. This principle emphasizes the importance of having a system of graduated sanctions in place to enforce compliance with rules and regulations related to the sustainable management of the resource.
Graduated sanctions involve a range of penalties or punishments that increase in severity as a user repeatedly violates the rules and regulations. The goal of graduated sanctions is not only to punish noncompliance but also to deter it from happening in the first place.
For example, in the case of a community fishery, graduated sanctions might involve warning users who violate fishing regulations for the first time, imposing fines for subsequent violations, and ultimately revoking a user's fishing license for repeated violations.
Effective graduated sanctions systems also involve clear and transparent rules and regulations, as well as a fair and impartial enforcement process. All users should be aware of the rules and regulations and the penalties for noncompliance, and enforcement should be carried out in a consistent and impartial manner to build trust and ensure that users feel that the system is fair.
Graduated sanctions can also be designed to include positive incentives for compliance. For example, users who comply with rules and regulations related to the sustainable management of the resource might be given priority access to the resource or other benefits.
Overall, the fifth design principle of graduated sanctions emphasizes the importance of having a system of penalties and punishments in place to enforce compliance with rules and regulations related to the sustainable management of the resource. By doing so, it can help to deter noncompliance, ensure that rules and regulations are followed, and promote fairness and trust in the management of the resource.
The sixth design principle identified by Elinor Ostrom for successful management of common-pool resources is conflict resolution mechanisms. This principle emphasizes the importance of having effective mechanisms in place for resolving conflicts among resource users.
Conflicts are a common occurrence in resource management, particularly when resources are scarce or when user groups have competing interests. Effective conflict resolution mechanisms can help to address these conflicts in a timely and fair manner, preventing them from escalating and potentially leading to resource depletion or destruction.
Conflict resolution mechanisms can take many different forms, including formal courts or tribunals, informal mediation or negotiation processes, or the creation of user committees or associations to facilitate communication and collaboration among users.
Effective conflict resolution mechanisms involve clear and transparent rules and procedures, as well as a fair and impartial decision-making process. All users should be aware of the conflict resolution mechanisms and have access to them, and the decision-making process should be carried out in a transparent and impartial manner to build trust and ensure that users feel that the process is fair.
For example, in the case of a community forest, conflict resolution mechanisms might involve creating a user committee or association that is responsible for facilitating communication and collaboration among different user groups, as well as for resolving conflicts that arise among users. The committee might use mediation or negotiation processes to address conflicts, or it might create a formal tribunal to make decisions in cases where conflicts cannot be resolved through informal processes.
Overall, the sixth design principle of conflict resolution mechanisms emphasizes the importance of having effective mechanisms in place for resolving conflicts among resource users. By doing so, it can help to prevent conflicts from escalating and potentially leading to resource depletion or destruction, and promote collaboration and cooperation in the sustainable management of the resource.

The seventh design principle identified by Elinor Ostrom for successful management of common-pool resources is the recognition of rights to organize. This principle emphasizes the importance of recognizing the right of resource users to form and participate in self-governing organizations that are responsible for managing the resource.
When resource users are able to organize and participate in decision-making processes related to the management of the resource, they are more likely to have a stake in the success of the system and to cooperate in its sustainable management. Moreover, by allowing users to organize and participate in decision-making processes, management systems can benefit from the knowledge and expertise of local users and can be tailored to the specific needs and conditions of the local community.
Recognizing the rights of resource users to organize can take many different forms, from allowing users to create formal associations or cooperatives to establishing informal community-based groups or committees. Regardless of the form that it takes, however, the key is to ensure that resource users have a meaningful say in decision-making processes related to the management of the resource.
For example, in the case of a community grazing system, recognizing the rights of resource users to organize might involve allowing users to form a grazing association or cooperative that is responsible for setting rules and regulations related to grazing, monitoring grazing practices, and enforcing compliance with the rules.
Overall, the seventh design principle of recognizing rights to organize emphasizes the importance of recognizing the right of resource users to form and participate in self-governing organizations that are responsible for managing the resource. By doing so, it can help to promote collaboration and cooperation in the sustainable management of the resource, as well as to ensure that management systems are tailored to the specific needs and conditions of the local community.

The eighth and final design principle identified by Elinor Ostrom for successful management of common-pool resources is nested enterprises. This principle emphasizes the importance of recognizing that the management of common-pool resources is often embedded in a larger social-ecological system, and that effective management requires coordination and cooperation at multiple levels.
Nested enterprises refer to the idea that management systems for common-pool resources should be designed to function at multiple scales, from the local to the global. This can involve creating nested hierarchies of decision-making and governance structures that enable coordination and cooperation among different levels of stakeholders.
For example, in the case of a community forestry system, nested enterprises might involve creating local-level management committees that are responsible for day-to-day management of the forest, as well as regional-level committees that are responsible for coordinating management across multiple forests in a particular region, and national-level committees that are responsible for setting policies and regulations related to forestry management at the national level.
Effective nested enterprises involve clear and transparent communication channels and decision-making processes across different levels of governance, as well as a recognition of the interdependencies between different levels of management. By coordinating management efforts across multiple scales, nested enterprises can help to ensure that management systems are tailored to the specific needs and conditions of the local community while also promoting sustainable resource use at larger scales.
Overall, the eighth design principle of nested enterprises emphasizes the importance of recognizing that the management of common-pool resources is often embedded in a larger social-ecological system and requires coordination and cooperation at multiple levels. By doing so, it can help to ensure that management systems are tailored to the specific needs and conditions of the local community while also promoting sustainable resource use at larger scales.


The first design principle identified by Elinor Ostrom for successful management of common-pool resources is the importance of clearly defining boundaries. In the context of co-living communities, this principle can be applied to address some of the most common issues faced by residents, such as conflicts over resource use, lack of accountability, and unclear community guidelines.
One of the primary ways to apply the first principle in co-living communities is by developing a shared vision and set of values for the community. This can involve a collaborative process of defining what the community stands for, what it hopes to achieve, and what values it will uphold. By doing so, residents can create a sense of belonging and shared responsibility that can help to reduce conflicts and foster cooperation.
Additionally, clearly defining boundaries in co-living communities involves establishing clear guidelines for resource use and community management. This can include developing rules and regulations related to noise levels, visitor policies, and common area use, as well as establishing mechanisms for resolving conflicts related to resource allocation.
One common issue faced by co-living communities is a lack of accountability. When guidelines and rules are not clearly defined, it can be difficult to hold individuals or groups accountable for their actions. To address this issue, co-living communities can establish mechanisms for reporting and addressing violations of community guidelines, such as a reporting system or a system of fines.
Another common issue faced by co-living communities is conflicts over resource use, such as disputes over shared kitchen spaces or laundry facilities. To address this issue, communities can establish clear guidelines for resource use, including scheduling systems or designated use times, as well as establishing mechanisms for resolving conflicts that arise.
Finally, the principle of clearly defining boundaries can also be applied to address issues related to external actors, such as neighboring communities or landlords. By establishing clear boundaries that separate the community from external actors and clearly defining the community's rights and responsibilities, residents can work together to negotiate and resolve conflicts that arise.
In conclusion, the first design principle identified by Elinor Ostrom can be applied to address some of the most common issues faced by co-living communities. By developing a shared vision and set of values, establishing clear guidelines for resource use and community management, addressing issues of accountability and external actors, and creating mechanisms for resolving conflicts related to resource allocation, co-living communities can promote sustainable resource use and foster a sense of community and collaboration among residents.
Want to print your doc?
This is not the way.
Try clicking the ⋯ next to your doc name or using a keyboard shortcut (
CtrlP
) instead.